Why we should adopt flexible exceptions to copyright

Herewith the column of two reports for the Australian Digital Alliance on copyright exceptions. Sounds abstruse but it’s quite engaging methinks.

On December 17, 1903, after years of tinkering with his brother Wilbur, Orville Wright took to the skies at Kitty Hawk, North Carolina. But the new age of aviation was born into a legal regime going back to Ancient Rome. Land owners’ held property rights to the infinite corridor of space “up to heaven” above their property and “down to hell” beneath it.

Aviators muddled through this legal minefield and most property holders’ didn’t care as they were suffering no harm. Incredibly, it took until 1942 for things to change when a landholder sued the US military for overflying his farm and upsetting his chickens!

Australia is suffering a similar kind of legal obsolescence today – with the US having made much more progress. In 1710, Queen Anne’s statute established copyright, which vouchsafed creators’ ability to economically exploit their work by requiring anyone who sought to copy it to obtain the creator’s permission. Meanwhile vehicles, warehouses and shops distributing and selling the book were not copying it, and so remained unentangled in the copyright regime as they assisted in the sale of the work.

This worked until, late in the twentieth century, copyright law had its own Orville and Wilbur Wright moment. Today virtually every operation of the internet triggers copyright liability like aviators tripped over chicken farmers’ property rights. If you’re reading this article on a digital device, a vast litany of copies were made to get it to you, from the search engine or feed from which you discovered it, to Fairfax’s server, to each router carrying the signal on every stage of its journey to and from your ISP (which also made digital copies) to the memory and screen on your own device. That’s a lot of copies! Yet each one plays the role of the delivery vehicle or the bookshop in the analogue world. Far from undermining the copyright holders’ position, all the ‘copies’ actually assist them distribute and so economically exploit their work. Yet at least in principle, to be legally secure, each of the owners of each bit of digital infrastructure that you used to learn of and download this article needs the copyright owner’s explicit permission to copy their work.

Indeed, in Lateral Economics’ research for the Australian Digital Alliance – an organisation comprising libraries, research and educational associations and internet infrastructure providers – we’ve shown that formally complying with all the red tape required to play it by the book would cost trillions – literally, more than the Australian economy produces!
Like someone with a stone in their shoe, lawmakers are forever seeking to fix this. But rather than systematic, principled change, our lawmakers have finessed the politics of the situation with a blizzard of ad hoc exceptions and accommodations.

In 2005 our parliamentarians learned to their bemusement that they and their families had been copyright pirates every time they ‘time-shifted’ the footy for later viewing. So they made it legal in 2006. Americans had been happily format-shifting songs from their (legitimately purchased) CDs to their computers and iPods, but it was illegal for Australians until 2006.

You can now format shift video tape and broadcast radio but not internet audio or video downloads. And our Copyright Act is an impenetrable tangle of red tape. For instance the 1,600 words of Section 49 allow libraries and archives to supply copies of documents to researchers but also requires each scan to be destroyed after use so it must be rescanned afresh next time.

Where we’ve erected a copyright “Nanny State”, the US doctrine of “fair use” establishes a general framework within which the right judgements can be made in each circumstance. Amongst other things it looks to:
• the purpose of use (was it commercial, or competing with the copyright holder?);
• the extent of the use; and critically,
• the effect of the use on the copyright holder’s market.

Without a flexible exception like this, needless obstacles remain in the way of investment and innovation in our copyright industries and to industries that are inextricable parts of the copyright eco system like education, professional services and internet infrastructure. If a flexible exception improved such industries’ productivity growth by just a tiny fraction, Lateral Economics simulations suggest that, though they’d start small, the gains would grow over a decade to around $600 million annually.

If that sounds too abstract, consider this. Businesses like Apple, Facebook, Dropbox, Yahoo, Linked in, Google, Amazon and eBay all depend on the US test of “fair use” to defend their numerous innovations against frivolous or unreasonable claims against them for inadvertent copyright breaches. Together those businesses are worth over a trillion dollars. No wonder other countries with an eye to growing their digital economies – like Singapore – have got with the program and replaced much of their birds nest of copyright exceptions with “fair use”.

Postscript: The podcast of the column Copyright Exceptions – with James O’Loghlin 16.9.12

This entry was posted in Economics and public policy, Intellectual Property, IT and Internet, Web and Government 2.0. Bookmark the permalink.
Subscribe
Notify of
guest

4 Comments
Oldest
Newest Most Voted
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments
Patrick
Patrick
11 years ago

Well I certainly agree with that. A friend just started law and wanted input on good areas of practice for a long-term lucrative global career.

IP was high on my list!

But I would go much further than this. For example I would severely restrict ‘design’ patents. I would also raise considerably the bar for injunctive relief – I would prefer that damages be almost invariably in the form of mandatory licence fees, with it being nearly impossible to obtain injunctive relief in cases such as Samsung v Apple.

john r walker
11 years ago

Good stuff.
Fair use is the necessary other side of copyright as an individual right.
Fair use comes out of an American constitutional context, how we could adapt it to the common law/case law concept of fair dealing is not clear to me, but expect it can be done.

Mandatory licensing is the worst solution, it creates “would be user rights groups” that are not based on free consent I.e it creates unrepresentative groups that are naturally opposed to both fair use and copyright as a individual right: there are no compulsory management fees in fair use and individual rights.

john r walker
11 years ago

Ps I was in the state library the other day looking up some hand drawn maps by Myles Dumphy , one of these maps was a hand copy (made in 1960) of a map drawn by myles father in 1920 . These maps were donated to the library by the right holder(s) and were never commercially printed. Because the copy was made post 1955 I could not use the library photocopier – provably Morehouse Vs Uni of NSW ?- but I could use my own camera …