
The current round of hearings at the royal commission into misconduct in the banking, superannuation and financial services industry has been notable on many levels. Thus far, the much anticipated grilling of the industry super funds has been a fizzer for their critics.
Ian Silk, who has been chief executive officer of the largest industry fund, the A$140 billion AusSuper, since 2006, was unruffled in his time in the witness box, in stark contrast to the caning given to NAB’s super fund trustees who preceded him.
Likewise, for David Elia, the CEO of hospitality and tourism industry fund Hostplus, a position he has held since 2003. He said that as of July this year, Hostplus had $34.5 billion funds under management on behalf of just over 1.1 million members, many of them very young, in part-time entry level casual employment.
Elia took the first opportunity he was given to remind the commission how, despite needing to consider the cohort of disengaged youngsters whose money his fund was managing, it has nevertheless thrived, with the Hostplus MySuper product ranked as the best performing fund, net of investment fees and tax over one, three, five, seven, 15 and 20 years.
What was notable?
Unlike their for-profit counterparts, two of the country’s largest and most influential super funds were represented by their chief executives, both of whom could claim long-term outperformance over their tenures.
Neither of them obfuscated or tried to hide behind weasel words. And they couldn’t – and didn’t – trot out the excuse so often used by their banking counterparts that they weren’t in the job at the time, or weren’t told anything, when (insert allegation of poor behaviour or regulatory breach here) occurred.
On the evidence so far, the industry funds’ CEOs have not left themselves open to the same allegations of bad behaviour and putting their members last that have so damaged the rest of the financial services sector.
Their banking CEO counterparts will soon get their respective days in the spotlight.
The excellent, but paywalled original is here.
It’s one of those basic economic illiterate truisms IMO: profit-driven funds split the return on investment between the shareholders and the people who provide the funds, industry funds give all the income to their people. It’s just obvious, my gut says so, that when you split the return with the shareholders you get less. Well dur Fred.
What we need is some whizz-bang econoboffin badger to show us that even after the profit has been skimmed off there’s more left for the fund-providers because of incentives or something. Like the incentive of not having a lamp-post with your name on it come the revolution encourages the industry fund managers to consider the longer term. “longer term” in todays market theory being “more than 3 months”… but soon it will be “longer than one second” just as soon as the high speed trading kiddies manage to securitise, commoditise and tradefuscate everything.
On that note, Nicolas, have you given thought to imposing frequency caps on trading? 1Hz seems ample, but 1mHz might be better, that’s closer to the speed actual humans live at. Just while you’re re-thinking the way central banking works and all :)
Ooops, there’s a haitch in Nicholas, sorry.
Yes, limiting trading seems like it could generate more benefits than costs in lots of circumstances. One thought I have is to open the markets for a week or so every quarter and leave them closed the rest of the time. That way you can try to get all information out before they open – reducing insider trading. But it’s difficult to know the relative costs and benefits.
might the reason be the retail funds knew they were for it so the CEOs sent in lessers but the Industry funds knew just the opposite so the CEOs turned up.
Yep you do not need to be einstein to expect Industry funds to out perform retail funds as they regularly do. Better performance and lower costs. dur indeed Fred
Indeed, and a single fund that accumulated ALL those compulsory savings would have almost negligible management fees and, because of the massive pooling, would certainly get a better risk/return ratio.
We could pay from that fund a defined benefit pension – a life annuity with a reversionary survivor pension – proportionate to peoples’ contributions (perhaps with some floors and caps to make the whole thing weakly progressive). Think how much simpler, fairer and more efficient that would be.
Oh wait – didn’t Otto Bismarck think of this idea first?
DD
Was this a option that was considered when the system was first designed?
No. It’s called “social security” and is the way many developed countries – including the US – fund retirement. Otto von Bismarck created the first such scheme in the 1880s.
I see…
DD
BTW your reply might take the biscuit for not answering a
question …
Legislation for a Bismarck style retirement income system was passed by parliament in 1939, however the war got in the way ( one of the sweetness for the introduction of a federal war emergency income tax in 1942 was that after the war the money would go to pensions and the like.)
In 1991 the Industrial Relations Commission the Commission:
“recommended that the Government convene a national conference on superannuation involving all relevant parties to consider issues such as non-compliance; the extension of award superannuation to all awards, including state awards; building more flexibility into award-based superannuation; the extension of superannuation to casual and part-time employees; and the role of the Commission in the long-term agenda for ensuring appropriate retirement incomes.
The Government opted not to act on the Commission’s recommendations. Instead, in the 1991-92 Budget, the Government announced that it would introduce a mandatory superannuation system through the implementation of the Superannuation Guarantee.”
In 2021 the thirty years will be up could be interesting to read the cabinet papers re the reasons why the government at the time chose not to act on the Commissions recommendations .
I was on the inside (albeit as a junior person) of these arguments in 1991. My indiscreet description (note I’ve not changed :-) ) of the government’s proposal as “founded on a series of outright economic fallacies and innately regressive” actually cost me a promotion opportunity, so naturally I’m not an objective observer here.
But suffice it to say that the prospect of jobs for union bureaucrats as fund trustees was not totally absent from some players’ minds. That and a really stupid “private=good public=bad” mindset in the Treasury of the time. It was a bizarre alliance between economic ignoramuses who believed the policy was completely costless because “the boss will pay it all anyway” and self-styled economic rationalists who were not economic rationalists at all.
DD
is this a fair summary of the history?
In particular is this section basically correct?
BTW Is that the same K W Hancock ; one of the founding fathers of Environmental History ?
(Sorry to go on ;-)
Casey’s introduction to the second reading of the NATIONAL HEALTH AND PENSIONS INSURANCE BILL 1938 is an interesting read.
And how little do things change :
[ the Hansard figures are scanned can’t copy-paste them.]
In 1909-10 the cost of aged and invalid pensions was 1.433 million pounds, by 1929-30 it had risen to 10.791 pounds.
[again the Hansard figures are scanned can’t copy-paste]
The percentage of the population aged over 65 had risen from 2.5% to 6.5%.
They also discuss the main problem with the introduction of a scheme such as this; Because it takes about 30-40 years before most of the people covered by it have contributed enough, for long enough to cover the actual costs of the system, it will in the short to medium term , increase not decrease the net cost to the government of payments for aged and invalid support:
The National Health and Insurance Bill 1938 was passed, but the scheme was not enacted.
That could because of “section 55 of the Constitution” they :
It may be that “later stage” never arrived?
BTW am surprised that there is very little in the way of published histories of our super and pensions systems evolution.
Actually, read Kewley (1972) for a properly comprehensive history, or shorter but more recent and available online:
Herscovitch, Andrew and Stanton, David. History of Social Security in Australia [online]. Family Matters, No. 80, 2008: 51-60. Availability: ISSN: 1030-2646. [cited 26 Aug 18].
DD
thanks will look it up